Agricultural Supply Response: A Survey
- 1 March 1989
- journal article
- research article
- Published by Wiley in Agricultural Economics
- Vol. 3 (1) , 1-22
- https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.1989.tb00068.x
Abstract
This paper surveys the literature on agricultural supply response to prices in developing countries. Empirical estimates of elasticities depend both on the methodology adopted and on country‐specific factors relating to technology, economic structure and macro constraints. The paper seeks to establish some general conclusions on supply responsiveness within these limitations. Supply response to output prices at the aggregate and at the crop levels is considered first. Crop‐specific acreage elasticities range between zero and 0.8 in the short run while long‐run elasticities tend to be higher — between 0.3 and 1.2. Yield elasticities are smaller and less stable than acreage elasticities. Clearly, inter‐crop pricing can be relied upon to effect shifts in the commodity composition of agricultural output. Evidence also suggests that supply elasticities vary systematically with such factors as price and yield risks, multiple‐cropping, the importance of the crop, farm incomes, farm size, tenancy and literacy. The most controversial and important aspect of supply response is the effect on aggregate agricultural output of agriculture's terms of trade. Conventional time‐series estimates range from 0.1 to 0.3. A major cross‐country study reports an aggregate elasticity as high as 1.66. It is argued that cross‐country estimates are apt to exaggerate aggregate responsiveness while time‐series studies underestimate it somewhat. For LDCs, a tentative range of 0.4 to 0.5 seems plausible. Hence, the distributive effects of the terms of trade are likely to be more significant than the allocative effects. Asian evidence shows that only a third of the inter‐country differences in fertilizer use can be attributed to fertilizer price policies. Provided new technologies and infrastructure are in place, fertilizer subsidies can help in technology diffusion and in overcoming credit constraints. The choice between price supports and input subsidies will depend on a variety of country‐ or situation‐specific factors. Nevertheless, a significant general factor favoring price supports is that they can more easily be coupled with price stabilization goals than input subsidies. Though sparse, the available evidence on the response of marketed surplus suggests that price policy is not a reliable instrument for regulating inter‐sectoral trade.Keywords
This publication has 25 references indexed in Scilit:
- A Model of an Agricultural Household in a Multi-Crop Economy: The Case of KoreaThe Review of Economics and Statistics, 1981
- An econometric application of the theory of the farm-householdJournal of Development Economics, 1979
- An analysis of price and output behavior in the Indian economy: 1951–1973Journal of Development Economics, 1979
- Price Support versus Input Subsidy for Food Self‐Sufficiency in Developing CountriesAmerican Journal of Agricultural Economics, 1976
- Incentives to Invest in New Agricultural Inputs in North IndiaEconomic Development and Cultural Change, 1972
- PRICE RESPONSE OF MARKETED SURPLUS OF FOODGRAINSOxford Economic Papers, 1971
- Price and Output Response of Marketed Surplus of Foodgrains: A Cross‐Sectional Study of Some North Indian VillagesAmerican Journal of Agricultural Economics, 1970
- Price Elasticity of the Marketed Surplus of a Subsistence CropJournal of Farm Economics, 1966
- A Theoretical Analysis of the Impact of Food Surplus Disposal on Agricultural Production in Recipient CountriesJournal of Farm Economics, 1963
- The Demand for Fertilizer: An Economic Interpretation of a Technical ChangeJournal of Farm Economics, 1958